Register For Our Mailing List

Register to receive our free weekly newsletter including editorials.

Home / 572

Clime time: Do budget deficits create inflation?

Macroeconomic analysis is extremely useful in explaining both the past and describing the present. Whilst its utility at forecasting the future is subject to debate – in my view it is a pointless one. That is because there can be no doubt that macro events constantly move markets. Simply reflect (if you need a recent example) upon how markets reacted to the announcement of Australia’s June CPI – the share market lifted, bond yields fell and the AUD sank, all within minutes of the data release. Then when there were signs (a few days later) of the US economy slowing with poor industrial output and weak employment data - the equity market slumped, bond yields collapsed and the AUD rallied as the USD devalued on higher probabilities that the Federal Reserve will cut cash rates in September. Macro events caused a liquidity rush towards assets regarded as low risk or defensive.

Whilst macro readings have an immediate effect on daily prices of assets, these prices are driven by sentiment shifts that are magnified in large part by traders and hedge funds. Long-term investors reflect on macro-observations to reconsider their acquisition (accumulation) price of assets or adjust their thoughts for asset allocation. Traders jump in, trying either to front run the trend or to stimulate short-term price movements for their advantage. They seldom have a thoughtful macro approach and are increasingly matching wits with computer-driven trading programs. The result is short-term price volatility that often reflects little of longer-term consequence and are the result of a programmed thought process – human into computer, and reflects noise rather than analysis.

The importance of both macro analysis and macro thought is not necessarily about forecasting the actual economic numbers. Rather, it is about connecting the projected economic outcomes with a considered view about how the new information might influence one’s expectations of returns from the various investment asset classes.

Invariably, the world economy grows each year and global recessions are rare – over the last 40 years there have been just two – the GFC and the Covid pandemic. Therefore, almost invariably, long-term investment returns result from staying invested and from compounding returns.

Economic dogma is everywhere

To undertake macro analysis requires more than a dogmatic approach to economic theory. However, much economic analysis has become overwhelmed with economic group think driven by Central Bank speak. For example, quantitative easing (QE) was widely adopted as the major monetary policy tool that dominated economic management following the GFC – but which Central Bank openly admits to it or explains its precise processes and objectives?

This introduction brings me to discuss the topic featured in my headline – “Do budget deficits create inflation?”

They can and have, but they don’t always. At present in Australia, I would argue that an extremely focused inflation-fighting budget (substantial attacks on both the cost of living and of doing business) would see a budget deficit that would drive down inflation and interest rates. Breaking an inflation cycle can be undertaken by aggressive fiscal policy. Importantly, it would be a fiscal policy (i.e. a deficit) that is highly consistent with fiscal policies around the world.

It does not take too many observations of major economies and their fiscal outcomes to show that fiscal deficits did not create inflation following the GFC. More pointedly, specific observations of Japanese fiscal outcomes (massive fiscal deficits) since 2000 did not lead to runaway inflation.

So why is there a chorus of claims by so many economists, commentators, and politicians that the government needs to reign in its expenditure or run a budget surplus to fight inflation? Why is there a dogmatic belief that a budget deficit will add to inflationary pressures? Why is there little analysis of government deficits to differentiate between those that attack inflation outcomes as opposed to those that add to them?

Before touching on Australia’s fiscal outlook and inflation, let's look at world inflation at present and investigate the history of US and Japanese budgets, their debt blowouts and inflation outcomes.

First, inflation across the world’s major economies has peaked. It was clearly stoked by the consequences of Covid and the Ukraine war. Indeed, inflation surged in 2022 to exceptional levels reminiscent of the 1970s when an oil price shock created ‘cost inflation’ across the world.

Further, the inflation surge had nothing to do with the budget outcomes or policies of major economies. Whilst all major economies are suffering large fiscal deficits, those deficits were in existence prior to Covid – but just at lower levels compared to GDP.


Source: Bloomberg

The following chart from Trading Economics compares the Japanese budget outcomes to inflation outcomes over the last 25 years. Fiscal deficits since the GFC have rarely been less than 4% of GDP and surged to 10% in Covid. Meanwhile, inflation readings have hovered around zero, with a mild outbreak in 2015 and a more recent surge following Covid.

There is no discernible correlation between Japan’s large budget deficits and inflation. Indeed, the opposite is true. On reflection, one could argue that the maintenance of extremely low interest rates (sometimes negative) added to dis-inflation in Japan. There is too little reflection by economists on the role of the cost of money (credit) on the cost of living or the cost of doing business.

The next chart covers US fiscal and inflation outcomes over the last ten years.

It is worth remembering that the US government has only achieved 2 fiscal surpluses over the last 50 years. More recently from 2014 to 2019, the deficit sat around 4% of GDP and inflation hovered between negligible and 2%.

Simply stated, fiscal deficits did not result in an inflation surge in the US in the period from the GFC to Covid. However, a surging fiscal deficit created by 2 unforeseeable events (Covid and Ukraine), with its far-flung range of global economic and financial consequences (e.g. supply-line disruptions, shortages of goods, labour market upheavals, power price spikes, working from home, etc) resulted in but did not create inflation from 2022 to 2024.

In Australia, observations of fiscal deficits (2014 to 2020) show no correlation with inflation. Whilst commentators point to a surge in fiscal deficits during Covid (7% of GDP) that pre-empted an inflation surge coming out of Covid, that is not indicative of any economic connection. The inflation flowed from supply dislocation, recovering demand and energy price surges. The deficit directly flowed from Covid.

What does this mean for investors?

My suggestion is that whilst investors should note reality, acknowledge Central Bank manipulation, and watch the daily trading noise, they should ignore much of the economic commentary, especially that which originates from traders or proffered by politicians.

There is too little commentary that is focused on the core of investing – understanding the calculation of the risk-free rate of return and how it is or should be calculated?

Bond yields are a fundamental case in point. What is the common explanation for Australia’s 'AAA-rated' ten-year bonds yielding 0.7% higher than 'BBB-rated' Greek bonds? The answer lies in the QE policy of the European Central Bank. It is the result of monetary manipulation and Australia’s dogmatic approach to economic management.

Why is this important?

It explains why bond yields have increasingly decoupled from inflation readings. Also, that the normal measure of risk-free return is less emphatic than it was prior to the turn of this century.

That is not a judgement as to whether this development is good or bad, but rather that it exists and should be acknowledged.

To me this means the following for macroeconomic outcomes for the rest of this decade:

  1. Government deficits (US, European and Japan) will not be reined in;
  2. Government debt (US, European and Japan) will remain at high levels;
  3. Interest rate settings will be driven lower (by Central Banks) to reduce government debt servicing costs;
  4. QE will therefore return in waves as Central Banks are forced to deal with government debt through manipulating bond markets;
  5. Government bonds remain low returning asset classes and will struggle to match inflation;
  6. Economic downturns in major economies (ex-China and India) will be mild and so will economic upturns – think Japan over the last 20 years.

Importantly, it suggests a return to economic management policies that dominated prior to Covid. That in turn drives the tailwinds of 'asset inflation' rather than 'consumer price inflation'.

As for Australia, I have a strong view that continued asset price inflation will mean that the housing crisis will soon overwhelm economic focus and require a complete reset of both fiscal management and monetary policy. Dogmatic economic thoughts will need to be jettisoned to ensure that housing is affordable for future generations.

What should happen?

Policies need to be developed to prepare for a managed decline in housing prices and these include:

  1. Targeted and aggressive fiscal deficits designed to drive down cost inflation;
  2. Aggressive fiscal policy aimed at increasing housing supply;
  3. Well-designed migration policy to slow population growth whilst tooling the workforce for needed essential skills;
  4. Mild QE policy through the issuance of bonds to move marginal housing loans (negligible equity loans) from the banks to the public sector, so that price declines can be managed; and
  5. A reset of credit policy by regulating the requirement for higher minimum deposit ratios for housing loans.

There is nothing wrong with fiscal deficits if they are appropriately set for a desired economic outcome. Attacking the cost of living, the cost of doing business and the cost of housing are proper reasons to have a fiscal deficit. However, it does require a breakaway from dogmatic economic thought and an ability to acknowledge the dramatic changes that have occurred in economic management over the last few decades.

 

John Abernethy is Founder and Chairman of Clime Investment Management Limited, a sponsor of Firstlinks. The information contained in this article is of a general nature only. The author has not taken into account the goals, objectives, or personal circumstances of any person (and is current as at the date of publishing).

For more articles and papers from Clime, click here.

 

10 Comments
Peter
August 11, 2024

Wage rises, low productivity and crazy electricity generation policies contribute to inflation as well as excess demand.

Dimitri Burshtein
August 09, 2024

Hi John.

Thanks for the commentary. However, you have not mentioned perhaps the most important thing in inflation management - money supply.

I can't attach images to this post, but if you look at page 14 of the RBA's latest chart pack here .... https://www.rba.gov.au/chart-pack/pdf/chart-pack.pdf?v=2024-08-08-14-41-40

it suggests that interest rate policy in AU has probably reached the point of diminishing, or even negative, marginal returns.

Any further interest rate increases will likely kill inflation by killing the economy. Another recession the government will chose to have.

Another dimension on fiscal policy impacting inflation is that all AU govs are increasing their spending/taxing as a proportion of GDP. This means that they are transferring more and more resources (by force) from higher productivity activities to lower productivity activities. This compresses aggregate supply.

And speaking of productivity, the government's non fiscal policies - including industrial relations, energy policy, industry policy, regulation - also dampen productivity. These, and the government's rising share of the economy both contribute to a drag on aggregate supply - the other side of the inflation coin.

Inflation is a product of bad government policy and we currently have the culmination of 20 years of bad government policy. Unfortunately, the current government just continues to pile more on.

Dudley
August 09, 2024

"most important thing in inflation management - money supply.": Just right: A smidgen of deflation to go with positive interest rates. Eliminates tax on imaginary (inflationary) interest.

John Abernethy
August 09, 2024

Thanks Dimitri

The management of the public service, the waste of tax payer money through the lack of productivity is well noted.

The current year ( FY25) budget deficit forecast is already questionable. Iron Ore price assumptions wrong and GDP growth for 2025 upgraded ( by the RBA).

Further, the budget deficit is dominated by the continued blow out in NDIS ( mismanaged policy) and the payment of Defined Benefit Pensions that could be paid by the Future Fund.

I maintain that fiscal policy could be much more aggressively set - yes and be funded from public sector productivity benefits - to target cost of living relief and break the wages catch up claims that continue to flow ( see services inflation).

I would have had a $1000 electricity rebate ( $2000 for small business) for all households that could have been adjusted or clawed back ( income test ) when tax returns for FY25 are lodged. That alone would have seriously attacked cost inflation and been appropriately targeted.

Warren Bird
August 14, 2024

Diitri, you said 'it's about money supply growing faster than production'. Not sure what you mean by that exactly.

In Fisher's identity, MV = PT the PT bit refers to nominal production. Money supply will grow faster than PT if the velocity of money circulation (V) is slowing. Although the old Chicago School assumption of constant V isn't valid, it is a slow moving thing and for many analytical purposes it's valid to see that M grows in line with nominal production pretty much all the time. Measurement issues arise, of course, so you need to look at this over time, but the relationship is pretty strong.

But perhaps you meant that 'it's about money supply growing faster than real production'. In which case, that as ALWAYS the case, unless you have constant deflation.

The policy issue is to get the mix right so that P is an inflation rate that is acceptable. In most countries these days they have a fixed inflation target, though Australia has been a little more flexible in recognition of inflation index calculation issues and the imprecision of all data and forecasts!

I think we're in partial agreement in that government policies since the Hawke-Keating and Howard-Costello eras have been sub-optimal in terms of getting the mix of P and T growth right. The lack of continued market reforms to enhance productivity - and some negative steps in the other direction - has exposed us to all sorts of disruptions, such as the much-touted supply disruptions during COVID and in the oil market when Russia invaded Ukraine. This has reduced the potential growth of T (real output) and increased the trend growth of P (inflation) for any given trend growth in M.

That's not quite the same thing as saying the inflation is only about money supply growth, though it's obvious to me that M got out of hand during COVID and policy was too slow to respond because that key piece of data was completely ignored. That's why inflation got as high as it did. There's a risk that the same mistake is being made now, with M growth having slowed sharply more recently, as I wrote about in my article.

Finally, I might add that one policy which - until very recently - has supported productivity growth has been the inflation-targeting regime of the RBA. Keeping inflation low and relatively stable for a few decades was definitely a support for productivity growth. Indeed, that's one of the reasons that targeting 'practical price stability' is so important. Can't blame the RBA for our poor productivity performance, as they did their bit. I hope they get their mojo back and we can look forward to an on-going lack of the distorting noise that inflation brings to the economic picture.

Barry
August 10, 2024

Exactly Dimitri.

It is the expansion of the money supply that causes inflation, more than anything else.

Warren Bird
August 11, 2024

I've written a lot about this lately.

I'm not such a Friedmanite that I would argue that expanding money supply causes inflation. I'd say that it facilitates it, by allowing the causal gap between aggregate demand and supply in the economy to get and remain wide.

My main argument in articles like last my recent FirstLinks one (https://www.firstlinks.com.au/vital-yet-forgotten-indicator-inflation-holds-good-news) is that the money supply is an indicator of how quickly monetary policy is working. Other things - like fiscal policy - can help or hinder it working, but if you want to know if interest rate increases are dampening credit demand then look at broad money growth. Had the money data been given any thought in 2020 then the RBA would have known that the fears about the pandemic that triggered ultra-low rates were not being realised, that credit was expanding rapidly and that this was telling us that an inflationary imbalance was building. Higher rates in 2021 would have been the right policy response and headed off most or all of the "crisis" we now have.
I don't agree therefore that the current inflation situation is because of "20 years of nad government policies". For most of the last 20 years we had an outstanding macro environment. It's the policies of the last 3 years that have been problematic.
We'd have had issues - like housing market stresses - and productivity has struggled. But to me that just means that the rates of P and T growth in MV=PT have shifted for any given M growth. A bit lower T and a bit higher P. Monetary policy has the most to say about the P part, but fiscal and microeconomic policies have much to say about T.

Dimitri Burshtein
August 14, 2024

It's about money supply in the absolute. It is about money supply growing faster than production.

It has been 20 years plus of government policy to retard production. High taxes. Sovereign market interventions. Regulation. Energy. Buckets of sand into the economic gears.

Paul
August 08, 2024

Brilliant. Why don't we have people like this advising The Treasurer, Treasury, The RBA where the people cannot think beyond doing things the way they have always been done

John
August 08, 2024

If we use the same definition of a deficit for an individual as we use for the government then we may get insights.

If the government spends more than it collects in tax then it's a deficit. Most peo0le think that a government deficit is bad.

Years ago (for a single year) I spent much more that I earned so I ran a deficit. Was it a good thing? Absolutely. I bought a house. Best move ever. But I borrowed and ran a deficit. Would I repeat that decision, with the benefit of hindsight? You bet I would

So, likewise with government a deficit is neither good or bad. What makes the difference is what the deficit is used for

 

Leave a Comment:

RELATED ARTICLES

Is 'The Great Australian Dream' a sham?

Can quantitative tightening help tame inflation?

Brace, brace, brace: The real issue behind the banking turmoil

banner

Most viewed in recent weeks

Welcome to Firstlinks Edition 568

As a recent import I've needed to adjust to Australia's retirement system. Not just to the new rules and jargon. But to how super funds are advertised and, quite frankly, how much bigger your retirement pots are.

  • 11 July 2024

A health scare changes my investment plans

Recently, I spent time in hospital for pneumonia. Health issues can clarify what really matters, and one thing became clear to me: 99% of what we think is important is either irrelevant or doesn’t need our immediate attention.

CPI may understate the rising costs of retirement

Rising prices have a big impact on retirement outcomes yet our most common gauge of inflation – the consumer price index – misses several important household costs for retirees.

Our finances should enable and not dictate our lives

Most people would prefer to have more money than less of it. But at what point do the trappings of wealth and success start to outweigh the benefits of striving for more?

Rethinking how retirees view the family home

Australia faces a wave of retirees at a stage where the superannuation system is still maturing. Better and fairer policy on the role of the family home as a retirement asset might help.

The tortoise wins in investing

For decades, it’s been a truism that taking greater risks with stocks should equate to higher returns. New research casts doubt on that and suggests investing in ‘boring’ stocks and industries may be a better bet.

Latest Updates

Investment strategies

Warren Buffett changes his mind at age 93

This month, Buffett made waves by revealing he’d sold almost 50% of his shares in Apple in the second quarter. The sale not only shows that Buffett has changed his mind on the stock but remains at the peak of his powers.

Financial planning

Wealth transfer isn't just about 'saving it up and passing it on'

We’ve seen how the transfer of wealth can work well, with inherited wealth helping families grow and thrive for generations, as well as how things can go horribly wrong. Here are tips on how to get it right.

Retirement

Navigating the risks of retirement

The biggest fear voiced by Australians prior to and during retirement is running out of money. Here's a detailed look at the key risks that should be considered when building a retirement income strategy.

Strategy

The numbers behind Australia’s record-breaking Olympics

Paris 2024 was Australia’s most successful Olympics, with 18 gold medals eclipsing the previous record of 17 set in Athens and Tokyo. This breaks down all the numbers and the reasons behind our success.

Investment strategies

How exposed is your portfolio to the AI story?

Questions are being asked of the AI story and the gargantuan investments that tech companies are pouring into it. If you don’t know how exposed your portfolio is to AI, now would be a good time to find out.

Infrastructure

Short-term panics create opportunity in real assets

Listed infrastructure companies often have fabulous assets, with monopoly positions and extremely reliable cash flows. But how do you identify the very best companies, and how do you pick them up at a reasonable price?

Economy

Why the RBA has been ineffective in curbing inflation

The RBA's prescription to hike rates may not work to lower inflation into the bank’s 2-3% target band. If anything, there appears to be a positive correlation between interest rates and inflation.

Sponsors

Alliances

© 2024 Morningstar, Inc. All rights reserved.

Disclaimer
The data, research and opinions provided here are for information purposes; are not an offer to buy or sell a security; and are not warranted to be correct, complete or accurate. Morningstar, its affiliates, and third-party content providers are not responsible for any investment decisions, damages or losses resulting from, or related to, the data and analyses or their use. To the extent any content is general advice, it has been prepared for clients of Morningstar Australasia Pty Ltd (ABN: 95 090 665 544, AFSL: 240892), without reference to your financial objectives, situation or needs. For more information refer to our Financial Services Guide. You should consider the advice in light of these matters and if applicable, the relevant Product Disclosure Statement before making any decision to invest. Past performance does not necessarily indicate a financial product’s future performance. To obtain advice tailored to your situation, contact a professional financial adviser. Articles are current as at date of publication.
This website contains information and opinions provided by third parties. Inclusion of this information does not necessarily represent Morningstar’s positions, strategies or opinions and should not be considered an endorsement by Morningstar.